Intended for healthcare professionals

Papers

Preventing fatal diseases increases healthcare costs: cause elimination life table approach

BMJ 1998; 316 doi: https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.316.7124.26 (Published 03 January 1998) Cite this as: BMJ 1998;316:26

This article has a correction. Please see:

  1. Luc Bonneux, medical epidemiologista (bonneux{at}mgz.fgg.eur.n1),
  2. Jan J Barendregt, mathematical economista,
  3. Wilma J Nusselder, demographera,
  4. Paul J Van der Maas, professor of public healtha
  1. a Department of Public Health, Erasmus University Rotterdam, PO Box 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, Netherlands
  1. Correspondence to: Dr Bonneux
  • Accepted 26 August 1997

Abstract

Objectives: To examine whether elimination of fatal diseases will increase healthcare costs.

Design: Mortality data from vital statistics combined with healthcare spending in a cause elimination life table. Costs were allocated to specific diseases through the various healthcare registers.

Setting and subjects: The population of the Netherlands, 1988.

Main outcome measures: Healthcare costs of a synthetic life table cohort, expressed as life time expected costs.

Results: The life time expected healthcare costs for 1988 in the Netherlands were £56 600 for men and £80 900 for women. Elimination of fatal diseases—such as coronary heart disease, cancer, or chronic obstructive lung disease—increases health- care costs. Major savings will be achieved only by elimination of non-fatal disease—such as musculoskeletal diseases and mental disorders.

Conclusion: The aim of prevention is to spare people from avoidable misery and death not to save money on the healthcare system. In countries with low mortality, elimination of fatal diseases by successful prevention increases healthcare spending because of the medical expenses during added life years.

Key messages

  • In countries with low mortality prevention of fatal diseases adds life years predominantly to old age, when disabling conditions are prevalent

  • If fatal diseases are eliminated, the medical costs of life extension at old age will generally be higher than the costs prevented. Prevention of disabling conditions, particularly mental disorders and musculoskeletal conditions, might both lower healthcare costs and improve public health

  • The aim of prevention is to save people from preventable morbidity and mortality not to save money

  • For the time being, prevention of disability should have the highest priority for future research

Introdution

In countries with low mortality, healthcare costs—which are already substantial—are on the rise. Health promotion, on the basis of the simple idea that by preventing illness, illness related costs will be prevented, has been hailed as the solution by some.1 It is doubtful, however, whether eliminating fatal diseases would cause a decrease in chronic morbidity. Healthcare needs terminate at death. Surviving means ageing, the strongest determinant for diseases such as osteoarthritis, osteoporosis and related fractures, cognitive decline, or loss of vision or hearing.

In demography, the effects of eliminating diseases are studied by cause elimination life tables.2 In such life tables a cause of death is eradicated and the life expectancy recalculated. By linking healthcare costs specific for a disease to the life table population, the consequences of having eliminated that disease as a cause of death, as well as of a source of costs, can be estimated.

Methods

In a previous study all healthcare costs in the Netherlands in 1988 (39 800 million Dutch guilders (fl), about £11 400 million at the 1988 exchange rate, for 14.8 million inhabitants) were allocated to age, sex, health- care sector, and primary diagnosis on the basis of comprehensive data on morbidity, mortality, and direct costs.3 4 5 About a quarter of all costs could not be allocated to a primary diagnosis, either through a lack of information or because of the non-personal nature of these costs (administration, general public health services, etc).

The healthcare costs were linked to the Dutch period life table for men and women for 1986-90.6 The expected costs represent the total costs of the life table cohort during their lifetime. These costs are divided by the initial size of the life table cohort—that is, the population at birth—to yield the life time expected costs for an individual (see Appendix 1). The interpretation of life time expected costs is analogous to the interpretation of life expectancy. The imaginary life table cohort was subjected to the unchanging costs of 1988 and the unchanging death rates of 1986-90 until extinction. The life expectancy is the sum of all the years a life table person is expected to live; the life time expected costs are the sum of all the healthcare costs that person is expected to incur during these life years. To calculate the effect of eradication, a specific disease was eliminated both as cause of death and as cause of costs: the cause elimination life table recalculates life expectancy and life time expected costs as if the eliminated disease had never existed. The life table assumed that people lived on average for half a year in the year of death. In the year that an eliminated cause of death would have occurred, people are then at risk of death from other causes during the entire year (instead of half a year) and remain fully at risk of other causes for the added life years. Only allocated costs were considered in the cause elimination life tables. Because cause elimination life tables are interpreted as stationary populations before or after the elimination of a disease7 the costs were not discounted. Cause specific mortality data were available for 5 year age groups up to the age of 84.6 After the age of 85, we assumed the cause of death ratio (deaths from the specific cause divided by all deaths) and the costs remained constant with rising age. This assumption underestimates the cost of added life years in the very old. Specific causes of death are underregistered at older ages, and health- care costs increase steadily with age.3 4 5 8

Results

Life expectancy in the Netherlands in 1986-90 was 73.5 years for men and 80.0 years for women. The lifetime expected costs at birth for all health care totalled fl198 000 (£56 600) for men and fl283 000 (£80 900) for women. About fl155 000 (£44 300) for men and fl219 000 (£62 600) for women was allocated to a primary diagnosis (1).

The 1 shows the inverse relation between fatality and costs: the highly lethal coronary heart diseases, causing nearly 19% of all deaths, account for only 2.7% of all healthcare costs. Mental disorders, including psychiatric diseases, mental handicaps, and dementia, are together responsible for only 0.6% of all deaths but account for 26% of the allocated healthcare budget. Elimination of coronary heart disease would substantially increase the burden on the healthcare budget as this would save few costs but add a considerable number of life years. Indeed, life expectancy would increase by about 1.9 years (2.5%), while costs would jump 6%. On the other hand, elimination of dementia would cause no noticeable change in life expectancy but would save 6% on the healthcare budget.

All deaths from 1986-906 and all allocated costs (in £1000) from 19885 caused by various disease groups and effects of elimination of these disease groups on life expectancy and life time expected costs. Numbers refer to ICD-9 codes.14 Values in parentheses are percentages. Those in life expectancy columns show relative change as consequence of elimination

View this table:

The elimination of coronary heart disease, cancer, and chronic obstructive lung disease—the present targets of health promotion—would augment healthcare costs substantially. The savings yielded by elimination of costs related to stroke and heart failure outweigh the costs associated with gains in life expectancy. Cancer is more fatal among men than among women, consequently the elimination of cancer would add more life years and therefore more costs among men.

Elimination of accidents and other unnatural causes of death adds life years and saves costs, in terms of both the high burden of morbidity and mortality. But the 1 shows that the largest gains are to be achieved through the elimination of mental disorders and musculoskeletal diseases: limited sources of lost life years but major sources of costs.

Discussion

Our analysis shows that lengthening life generally will increase healthcare needs, particularly needs for long term nursing care as most life years are added to old age. This is not a bad thing; prevention can hardly be blamed if it reaches its target and lowers mortality. Life saving treatment, such as antibiotic treatment of severe infections or oral rehydration in severe diarrhoea, has the same consequences. Indeed, we firmly believe that primary prevention, such as an effective antismoking policy, is an excellent buy. But that does not imply that no bill has to be paid. Our paper contradicts popular belief that prevention might “prevent” healthcare costs.1 Acute medical costs may be averted, but the considerable needs for long term nursing care of frail elderly people can but increase.

Eliminating causes in a life table demonstrates an unquestionable truth: we all have to die. If we eliminate a specific cause of death, we simply die later from another. In the meantime we grow older, become generally more disabled, and need more care.9 In the Netherlands, cardiovascular diseases and cancer were jointly responsible for nearly 70% of all deaths, yet accounted for a mere 17% of all healthcare costs, whereas the largely non-fatal diseases of the brain, joints, and bones, causing under 2% of all deaths, generated 35% of all costs (see 1). If fatal diseases are eliminated, healthcare costs during the added life years swamp the savings yielded by the eliminated disease, even if the intervention is radical and without extra costs. At any age, the imaginary population of the cause elimination life table spends less on health care per person yet total costs increase because more people remain alive, surviving to older ages when chronic morbidity and demands for health care are highest (1).

Figure1

Costs by age in life table of men and women subjected to death rates and to disease allocated costs from 1988. Areas under lines are life time expected costs. Dashed lines show effects of elimination of two major disease groups: one fatal (cardiovascular disease) and one non-fatal (musculoskeletal conditions)

As the debate has focused on healthcare costs,1 we took into account only medical costs. The non-medical costs of added life years, such as pensions and non-medical care for elderly people, would far outweigh any non-medical costs of disease and death.10

In view of the fact that our cost data are comprehensive, we were able to consider all health- care spending, including long term nursing care. 3 4 5 Previous studies have shown that in the United States payments for acute medical care are higher in the year before death, irrespective of age at death.11 Our results do not contradict these findings but demonstrate the high burden of chronic care for non-fatal diseases, which are not determined by death.

Cause elimination life tables are simple mathematical models based on the assumption of the independence of diseases. Only primary diagnoses are taken into account, while comorbidity is ignored. In real life, many diseases are not independent, and death is often the end of a complex process. Insights are garnered from parsimonious theoretical experiments, however, precisely because they simplify a complicated reality. Taking all relevant disease interactions into account would increase needs for data and complexity of models intolerably but would not change the conclusions in a meaningful way. Indeed, only when a disease process can be postponed without postponing mortality can morbidity and healthcare needs be “compressed” by prevention.2

From a humanitarian point of view, life is preferable to death and health to illness.13 The aim of health care is not to save money but to save people from preventable suffering and death. Moreover, the medical costs of added life years are trivial. Life extension would cost about £890 to £1400 per life year added, which few would consider unacceptable. But if prevention is used as an argument for constraining future healthcare expenditures, the medical expenses in the added life years are not insignificant and cannot be ignored. There is no evidence that healthcare costs are increasing because citizens live unhealthier lives. In fact, quite the contrary would seem to be the case.

We have become increasingly successful at postponing mortality until advanced ages. Old age, however, is associated not only with impending death but also with dementia, social isolation, osteoarthritis, hip fractures, and loss of vision and hearing. Even humble progress in disease prevention would have a tangible impact. Any potential savings on healthcare costs would be icing on that cake.

Acknowledgments

We thank Mrs Karen Gribling-Laird for her linguistic help.

Funding: This study is part of the technology assessment methods project and was funded by a grant from the Ministry of Health, Welfare, and Cultural Affairs, the Netherlands.

Conflict of interest: None.

Appendix

Life time expected costs (LEC) are calculated by


where Cx is the cost of all causes in the age interval (x, x+1). Nx is the number of people in the age interval (x, x+1) and Lx the person years lived in the age interval (x, x+1).

Eliminating a cause of death is based on the actuarial assumption that people dying from the specific cause in the age interval x, x+1 were considered to have been at a 0.5 year risk of dying from all other causes. The risk of dying at age × from all other causes, adjusted for competing causes,

Formula

where dx, is the number of deaths in age interval (x, x+1) due to the cause α, dx,-α is the number of deaths in age interval (x, x+1) due to all other causes than α, and lx is the number of survivors to age × (of the all causes life table cohort). The life table cohort is at risk for this adjusted force of mortality from other causes until extinction.2

The expected life time costs at birth after elimination of cause α (LEC-α) are given by

Formula

where Cx,-α represents the costs in the age interval (x, x+1) made for all diseases other than α and Lx,-α gives the life years lived in the age interval (x, x+1) after elimination of cause α.

Notes

Contributors: LB had the original idea for the present study. He helped in collecting the costing data, performed the life table analysis, and wrote the paper. JJB discussed the core ideas of demographic and economic methods and helped in developing the life tables and in writing the paper. WJN did previous work in the same line of research,9 gave the demographic data, and supervised the correct use and representation of the demographic methods. She corrected previous drafts. PJVan DerM is responsible for the technology assessment methods project and its main ideas, particularly the combination of comprehensive epidemiological, economic, and demographic methods. He supervised the collection of all data and commented on previous drafts. LB, JJB, and PJVan DerM are guarantors for the scientific integrity of the paper.

References

  1. 1.
  2. 2.
  3. 3.
  4. 4.
  5. 5.
  6. 6.
  7. 7.
  8. 8.
  9. 9.
  10. 10.
  11. 11.
  12. 12.
  13. 13.
  14. 14.
View Abstract